Taking a cue from my boss, I just finished this article on behavioral economics — a growing field that explores how, and why, flesh-and-blood humans don’t behave like the “rational” profit-maximizers that underpin most economic models. It seems to me there are some lessons here for the theory and practice of social change.

In a nutshell: calling for immediate action to address a long-term problem may prompt resistance from the emotional and fearful sides of our brains; but calling for delayed action may put emotional reactions on hold, and allow for a more sober (and potentially more favorable) response to the issue.

First off, there are myriad ways in which real people defy the predictions of simple economic models. Some well-known examples: real people fear losses more than we value gains, even though a “rational” economic actor would weigh them equally; humans punish bad behavior, even if it hurts our interests to do so; and we worry more about harms caused by people than harms caused by “nature” or chance (e.g., we fear terrorism more than car crashes, and murders more than heart disease).

Reader support helps sustain our work. Donate today to keep our climate news free. All donations DOUBLED!

And here’s something else: real human beings radically discount the importance of future events. Pleasure a year from now is little incentive, compared with pleasure right now; and the prospect of discomfort a year from now doesn’t seem particularly daunting. That’s why, when we’re faced with something good in the short term (for example, yummy yummy donuts), but bad in the long term (say, weight gain), the short-term view tends to win, hands down.

Grist thanks its sponsors. Become one.

OK, this is not exactly a new insight about human nature: a bird in hand has always been worth two in the bush. And economists have long used “discount rates” to downgrade the value of future events, based on how far they are from the present.

But what seemed genuinely new to me is this: studies of brain function have shed a bit of light into what’s actually going on when we discount the future.

Making any choice, whether short-term or long, activates the brain’s frontal cortex — the reasoning center. But when considering a short-term event, the limbic system — which governs emotional responses and intuitive cognition — kicks in too. And the limbic system doesn’t seem to care much about the future; its job is to maximize short-term gains.

Which leads to this odd result: in an experiment in which subjects are asked to choose between $20 right now, and $23 a month from now, the subjects’ limbic systems are activated — and they tend to choose $20 now. (Bird in hand and all that.) But change the offer to two future prospects — $20 in 2 weeks vs. $23 in one month — and the limbic system pipes down; the choice is strictly in the hands of the “rational” side of the brain. As a result, people are far more likely exercise patience and maximize their gains.

Grist thanks its sponsors. Become one.

Now, I’m probably reading way too much into this. But it struck me that there may be a lesson here for enacting long-term reforms — things we really want to do, but may be painful or risky in the short term. The trick may be in the timing: commit to it right now, but put off the starting date until later.

That’s more or less what California’s landmark greenhouse gas law does. It was passed this year, but the actual regulations (whatever they turn out to be) won’t go into effect until 2012. There are practical reasons for delaying the regulations: they have to figure out what they’re doing first. But perhaps because the program won’t start for another half-decade, the legislation appealed to the analytical part of legislators’ brains without kicking in their limbic systems. There was no fear of immediate economic effects or short-term electoral backlash.

Obviously, this could be a recipe for empty promises. And policy advocates — like everyone else — tend to value immediate action over nebulous future gains. That said, if there’s a long-term issue that can’t get past a short-term logjam, then maybe it’s wise to take a lesson from the behavioral economists, and find a way to appeal to people’s rational side without activating their fight-or-flight reflex.