Tom Friedman is in full-on green mode these days, which is a welcome change from his writing on Iraq. And his proposal yesterday — that the U.S. should declare a $4 price floor for a gallon of gas — is all right, although I’m not sure why we shouldn’t just raise the gas tax and make it a percentage of the pump price rather than a flat number.

But I’m interested in his introduction to the column:

Reader support makes our work possible. Donate today to keep our site free. All donations TRIPLED!

Imagine for a minute, just a minute, that someone running for president was able to actually tell the truth, the real truth, to the American people about what would be the best — I mean really the best — energy policy for the long-term economic health and security of our country. I realize this is a fantasy, but play along with me for a minute. What would this mythical, totally imaginary, truth-telling candidate say?

For starters, he or she would explain that there is no short-term fix for gasoline prices. Prices are what they are as a result of rising global oil demand from India, China and a rapidly growing Middle East on top of our own increasing consumption, a shortage of “sweet” crude that is used for the diesel fuel that Europe is highly dependent upon and our own neglect of effective energy policy for 30 years.

Grist thanks its sponsors. Become one.

Cynical ideas, like the McCain-Clinton summertime gas-tax holiday, would only make the problem worse, and reckless initiatives like the Chrysler-Dodge-Jeep offer to subsidize gasoline for three years for people who buy its gas guzzlers are the moral equivalent of tobacco companies offering discounted cigarettes to teenagers.

Now this is a funny juxtaposition, because that’s basically what Obama did. And, abetted by an oddly benign media, voters appeared to hear what he was saying, believe it, and appreciate the candor.

But there is a difference, behaviorally speaking, in arguing that the removal of an existing tax would be pointless and arguing that the imposition of a new tax would be good. The difference is similar to behavioral economics questions surrounding stimulus checks; consumers are more likely to spend them if they’re called bonuses than if they’re called refunds. The issue is perception. The exact determining factor may be status quo bias or loss aversion, but the job of a politician arguing in favor of increased taxes is sure to be a difficult one.

I mention this because I believe that on such the Yglesian formulation — that it’s better, politically and morally, to get the policy right — is the correct one. Telling Americans that they can be spared high fuel prices in this case is a lie, and eventually Americans will come to know it as such. Better to convey a message that will be borne out by the future, and better still to plan for it. The right thing to do is to push for solutions that will best serve the country over the long term.

Grist thanks its sponsors. Become one.

The question is, how to build support for increased taxes in a world where the support of experts, “experts,” and the media cannot be guaranteed? One route might be to offer something to voters for their money. Specifically, are you more likely to have success with a plan that refunds revenues elsewhere, or with a plan that spends money on alternatives? As popular as the plan to cut payroll tax rates to offset fuel or carbon taxes is, it is far too vulnerable to allegations of social security raiding. Local area polls tend to show support for tax increases to fund transit, but those polls are conducted in areas that will benefit directly from built transit.

It’s also possible that the kind of argument may make all the difference. In my view, the most compelling political arguments are nationalistic (e.g., higher gas taxes will reduce the amount of money we send to the Gulf) and employment-oriented (e.g., money spent with this revenue to build new infrastructure will create lots of jobs). But those aren’t really the reasons to pass higher gas taxes. They are fortuitous side effects.

The question is this: In speaking the truth on these issues, just how much truth should politicians speak? The gas tax episode demonstrates that under the right circumstances, the public can learn about and understand the merits of one policy versus another. Both those circumstances are unlikely to be obtained in future debates, which are themselves likely to be fiercer because of our behavioral aversion to change and new taxes.

We should never shy away from communicating the thinking beneath policies like carbon pricing or renewable portfolio standards, but it may be wise for greens to prepare themselves to make a complete, and perhaps a calculated, argument for the policies we need.